United States antitrust law
In the United States, antitrust law is a collection of federal and state government laws that regulates the conduct and organization of business corporations, generally to promote competition for the benefit of consumers. The main statutes are the Sherman Act of 1890, the Clayton Act of 1914 and the Federal Trade Commission Act of 1914. These Acts serve three major functions. First, Section 1 of the Sherman Act prohibits price-fixing and the operation of cartels, and prohibits other collusive practices that unreasonably restrain trade. Second, Section 7 of the Clayton Act restricts the mergers and acquisitions of organizations that would likely substantially lessen competition. Third, Section 2 of the Sherman Act prohibits the abuse of monopoly power.
Federal antitrust laws provide for both civil and criminal enforcement of antitrust laws. The Federal Trade Commission, the Antitrust Division of the U.S. Department of Justice, and private parties who are sufficiently affected may all bring civil actions in the courts to enforce the antitrust laws. However, criminal antitrust enforcement is done only by the Justice Department. U.S. states also have antitrust statutes that govern commerce occurring solely within their state borders.
The scope of antitrust laws, and the degree to which they should interfere in an enterprise's freedom to conduct business, or to protect smaller businesses, communities and consumers, are strongly debated. One view, mostly closely associated with the "Chicago School of economics" suggests that antitrust laws should focus solely on the benefits to consumers and overall efficiency, while a broad range of legal and economic theory sees the role of antitrust laws as also controlling economic power in the public interest. Nonetheless, a survey of 298 members of the American Economic Association taken in 2000 found a qualified consensus among economists where 71 percent generally agreed with the statement that "Antitrust laws should be enforced vigorously to reduce monopoly power from its current level", while a follow-up survey of 568 members of the AEA in 2011 found that 87 percent generally agreed with the statement "Antitrust laws should be enforced vigorously."
History
Although "trust" has a specific legal meaning, in the late 19th century the word was commonly used to denote big business, because that legal instrument was frequently used to effect a combination of companies. Large manufacturing conglomerates emerged in great numbers in the 1880s and 1890s, and were perceived to have excessive economic power. The Interstate Commerce Act of 1887 began a shift towards federal rather than state regulation of big business. It was followed by the Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890, the Clayton Antitrust Act of 1914 and the Federal Trade Commission Act of 1914, the Robinson–Patman Act of 1936, and the Celler–Kefauver Act of 1950.In the 1880s, hundreds of small short-line railroads were being bought up and consolidated into giant systems. People for strong antitrust laws argued that, in order for the American economy to be successful, it would require free competition and the opportunity for individual Americans to build their own businesses. As Senator John Sherman put it, "If we will not endure a king as a political power we should not endure a king over the production, transportation, and sale of any of the necessaries of life." Congress passed the Sherman Antitrust Act almost unanimously in 1890, and it remains the core of antitrust policy. The Act prohibits agreements in restraint of trade and abuse of monopoly power. It gives the Justice Department the mandate to go to federal court for orders to stop illegal behavior or to impose remedies.
Public officials during the Progressive Era put passing and enforcing strong antitrust high on their agenda. President Theodore Roosevelt sued 45 companies under the Sherman Act, while William Howard Taft sued almost 90. In 1902, Roosevelt stopped the formation of the Northern Securities Company, which threatened to monopolize transportation in the Northwest.
was a major company broken up under United States antitrust laws.
One of the better-known trusts was the Standard Oil Company; John D. Rockefeller in the 1870s and 1880s had used economic threats against competitors and secret rebate deals with railroads to build what was called a monopoly in the oil business, though some minor competitors remained in business. In 1911 the Supreme Court agreed that in recent years Standard had violated the Sherman Act. It broke the monopoly into three dozen separate companies that competed with one another, including Standard Oil of New Jersey, Standard Oil of Indiana, Standard Oil Company of New York, of California, Cleveland-based SOHIO - the parent of the trust, and so on. In approving the breakup the Supreme Court added the "rule of reason": not all big companies, and not all monopolies, are evil; and the courts are to make that decision. To be harmful, a trust had to somehow damage the economic environment of its competitors.
United States Steel Corporation, which was much larger than Standard Oil, won its antitrust suit in 1920 despite never having delivered the benefits to consumers that Standard Oil did. In fact, it lobbied for tariff protection that reduced competition, and so contending that it was one of the "good trusts" that benefited the economy is somewhat doubtful. Likewise International Harvester survived its court test, while other monopolies were broken up in tobacco, meatpacking, and bathtub fixtures. Over the years hundreds of executives of competing companies who met together illegally to fix prices went to federal prison.
In 1914 Congress passed the Clayton Act, which prohibited specific business actions if they substantially lessened competition. At the same time Congress established the Federal Trade Commission, whose legal and business experts could force business to agree to "consent decrees", which provided an alternative mechanism to police antitrust.
American hostility to big business began to decrease after the Progressive Era. For example, Ford Motor Company dominated auto manufacturing, built millions of cheap cars that put America on wheels, and at the same time lowered prices, raised wages, and promoted manufacturing efficiency. Welfare capitalism made large companies an attractive place to work; new career paths opened up in middle management; local suppliers discovered that big corporations were big purchasers. Talk of trust busting faded away. Under the leadership of Herbert Hoover, the government in the 1920s promoted business cooperation, fostered the creation of self-policing trade associations, and made the FTC an ally of "respectable business".
During the New Deal, attempts were made to stop cutthroat competition. The National Industrial Recovery Act was a short-lived program in 1933–35 designed to strengthen trade associations, and raise prices, profits and wages at the same time. The Robinson-Patman Act of 1936 sought to protect local retailers against the onslaught of the more efficient chain stores, by making it illegal to discount prices. To control big business, the New Deal policymakers preferred federal and state regulation —controlling the rates and telephone services provided by AT&T, for example— and by building up countervailing power in the form of labor unions.
The antitrust environment of the 70's was dominated by the case , which was filed by the U.S. Justice Department in 1969. IBM at the time dominated the computer market through alleged bundling of software and hardware as well as sabotage at the sales level and false product announcements. It was one of the largest and certainly the lengthiest antitrust case the DoJ brought against a company. In 1982, the Reagan administration dismissed the case, and the costs and wasted resources were heavily criticized. However, contemporary economists argue that the legal pressure on IBM during that period allowed for the development of an independent software and personal computer industry with major importance for the national economy.
In 1982 the Reagan administration used the Sherman Act to break up AT&T into one long-distance company and seven regional "Baby Bells", arguing that competition should replace monopoly for the benefit of consumers and the economy as a whole. The pace of business takeovers quickened in the 1990s, but whenever one large corporation sought to acquire another, it first had to obtain the approval of either the FTC, FCC or the Justice Department. Often the government demanded that certain subsidiaries be sold so that the new company would not monopolize a particular geographical market.
In 1999 a coalition of 19 states and the federal Justice Department sued Microsoft. A highly publicized trial found that Microsoft had strong-armed many companies in an attempt to prevent competition from the Netscape browser. In 2000, the trial court ordered Microsoft to split in two, preventing it from future misbehavior. The Court of Appeals affirmed in part and reversed in part. In addition, it removed the judge from the case for discussing the case with the media while it was still pending. With the case in front of a new judge, Microsoft and the government settled, with the government dropping the case in return for Microsoft agreeing to cease many of the practices the government challenged.
Cartels and collusion
Preventing collusion and cartels that act in restraint of trade is an essential task of antitrust law. It reflects the view that each business has a duty to act independently on the market, and so earn its profits solely by providing better priced and quality products than its competitors.The Sherman Act §1 prohibits "very contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce." This targets two or more distinct enterprises acting together in a way that harms third parties. It does not capture the decisions of a single enterprise, or a single economic entity, even though the form of an entity may be two or more separate legal persons or companies. In Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp. it was held an agreement between a parent company and a wholly owned subsidiary could not be subject to antitrust law, because the decision took place within a single economic entity. This reflects the view that if the enterprise has not acquired a monopoly position, or has significant market power, then no harm is done. The same rationale has been extended to joint ventures, where corporate shareholders make a decision through a new company they form. In Texaco Inc. v. Dagher the Supreme Court held unanimously that a price set by a joint venture between Texaco and Shell Oil did not count as making an unlawful agreement. Thus the law draws a "basic distinction between concerted and independent action". Multi-firm conduct tends to be seen as more likely than single-firm conduct to have an unambiguously negative effect and "is judged more sternly". Generally the law identifies four main categories of agreement. First, some agreements such as price fixing or sharing markets are automatically unlawful, or illegal per se. Second, because the law does not seek to prohibit every kind of agreement that hinders freedom of contract, it developed a "rule of reason" where a practice might restrict trade in a way that is seen as positive or beneficial for consumers or society. Third, significant problems of proof and identification of wrongdoing arise where businesses make no overt contact, or simply share information, but appear to act in concert. Tacit collusion, particularly in concentrated markets with a small number of competitors or oligopolists, have led to significant controversy over whether or not antitrust authorities should intervene. Fourth, vertical agreements between a business and a supplier or purchaser "up" or "downstream" raise concerns about the exercise of market power, however they are generally subject to a more relaxed standard under the "rule of reason".
Restrictive practices
Some practices are deemed by the courts to be so obviously detrimental that they are categorized as being automatically unlawful, or illegal per se. The simplest and central case of this is price fixing. This involves an agreement by businesses to set the price or consideration of a good or service which they buy or sell from others at a specific level. If the agreement is durable, the general term for these businesses is a cartel. It is irrelevant whether or not the businesses succeed in increasing their profits, or whether together they reach the level of having market power as might a monopoly. Such collusion is illegal per se.- United States v. Trenton Potteries Co., per se illegality of price fixing
- Appalachian Coals, Inc. v. United States,
- United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co.,
- Addyston Pipe and Steel Co. v. United States pipe manufacturers had agreed among themselves to designate one lowest bidder for government contracts. This was held to be an unlawful restraint of trade contrary to the Sherman Act. However, following the reasoning of Justice Taft in the Court of Appeals, the Supreme Court held that implicit in the Sherman Act §1 there was a rule of reason, so that not every agreement which restrained the freedom of contract of the parties would count as an anti-competitive violation.
- Hartford Fire Insurance Co. v. California, 113 S.Ct. 2891 5 to 4, a group of reinsurance companies acting in London were successfully sued by California for conspiring to make U.S. insurance companies abandon policies beneficial to consumers, but costly to reinsure. The Sherman Act was held to have extraterritorial application, to agreements outside U.S. territory.
- Fashion Originators' Guild of America v. FTC, 312 U.S. 457 the FOGA, a combination of clothes designers, agreed not to sell their clothes to shops which stocked replicas of their designs, and employed their own inspectors. Held to violate the Sherman Act §1
- Klor's, Inc. v. Broadway-Hale Stores, Inc., 359 U.S. 207 a group boycott is per se unlawful, even if it may be connected with a private dispute, and will have little effect upon the markets
- American Medical Association v. United States, 317 U.S. 519
- Molinas v. National Basketball Association, 190 F. Supp. 241
- Associated Press v. United States, 326 U.S. 1 6 to 3, a prohibition on members selling "spontaneous news" violated the Sherman Act, as well as making membership difficult, and freedom of speech among newspapers was no defense, nor was the absence of a total monopoly
- Northwest Wholesale Stationers v. Pacific Stationery, 472 U.S. 284 it was not per se unlawful for the Northwest Wholesale Stationers, a purchasing co-operative where Pacific Stationery had been a member, to expel Pacific Stationery without any procedure or hearing or reason. Whether there were competitive effects would have to be adjudged under the rule of reason.
- NYNEX Corp. v. Discon, Inc., 525 U.S. 128 the per se group boycott prohibition does not apply to a buyer's decision to purchase goods from one seller or another
Rule of reason
- Broadcast Music v. Columbia Broadcasting System, blanket licenses did not necessarily count as price fixing under a relaxed rule of reason test.
- Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical Society, 457 U.S. 332 4 to 3 held that a maximum price agreement for doctors was per se unlawful under the Sherman Act section 1.
- Wilk v. American Medical Association, 895 F.2d 352 the American Medical Association's boycott of chiropractors violated the Sherman Act §1 because there was insufficient proof that it was unscientific
- United States v. Topco Assocs., Inc., 405 U.S. 596
- Palmer v. BRG of Georgia, Inc., 498 U.S. 46
- National Soc'y of Prof. Engineers v. United States, 435 U.S. 679 ; ¶¶219-220 -
- NCAA v. Board of Regents of the University of Oklahoma, 468 U.S. 85 7 to 2, held that the National College Athletics Association's restriction of television of games, to encourage live attendance, was restricting supply, and therefore unlawful.
- California Dental Assn. v. FTC, 526 U.S. 756
- FTC v. Indiana Fed'n of Dentists, 476 U.S. 447
Tacit collusion and oligopoly
- Matsushita Electric Industrial Co., Ltd. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574 held that the evidence needed to show unlawful collusion contrary to the Sherman Act, must be enough to exclude the possibility of individual behavior.
- Bell Atlantic Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544 5 to 2, while Bell Atlantic and other major telephone companies were alleged to have acted in concert to share markets, and not compete in each other's territory to the detriment of small businesses, it was held that in absence of evidence of an agreement, parallel conduct is not enough to ground a case under the Sherman Act §1
- Interstate Circuit, Inc. v. United States, 306 U.S. 208
- Theatre Enterprises v. Paramount Distributing, 346 U.S. 537, no evidence of illegal agreement, however film distributors gave first film releases to downtown Baltimore theatres, and suburban theatres were forced to wait longer. Held, there needed to be evidence of conspiracy to injure
- United States v. American Tobacco Company, 221 U.S. 106 found to have monopolized the trade.
- American Tobacco Co. v. United States, 328 U.S. 781 after American Tobacco Co was broken up, the four entities were found to have achieved a collectively dominant position, which still amounted to monopolization of the market contrary to the Sherman Act §2
- American Column & Lumber Co. v. United States, 257 US 377 information sharing
- Maple Flooring Manufacturers' Assn. v. United States, 268 U.S. 563
- United States v. Container Corp., 393 U.S. 333
- Airline Tariff Publishing Company, settlement with the US Department of Justice
Vertical restraints
- Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. John D. Park and Sons, 220 U.S. 373 affirmed a lower court's holding that a massive minimum resale price maintenance scheme was unreasonable and thus offended Section 1 of the Sherman Antitrust Act.
- Kiefer-Stewart Co. v. Seagram & Sons, Inc., 340 U.S. 211 it was unlawful for private liquor dealers to require that their products only be resold up to a maximum price. It unduly restrained the freedom of businesses and was per se illegal.
- Albrecht v. Herald Co., 390 U.S. 145 setting a fixed price, minimum or maximum, held to violate section 1 of the Sherman Act
- State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3 vertical maximum price fixing had to be adjudged according to a rule of reason
- Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc. 551 U.S. 877 5 to 4 decision that vertical price restraints were not per se illegal. A leather manufacturer therefore did not violate the Sherman Act by stopping delivery of goods to a retailer after the retailer refused to raise its prices to the leather manufacturer's standards.
- Packard Motor Car Co. v. Webster Motor Car Co., 243 F.2d 418, 420, cert, denied, 355 U.S. 822
- Continental Television v. GTE Sylvania, 433 U.S. 36 6 to 2, held that it was not an antitrust violation, and it fell within the rule of reason, for a seller to limit the number of franchises and require the franchisees only sell goods within its area
- United States v. Colgate & Co., there is no unlawful action by a manufacturer or seller, who publicly announces a price policy, and then refuses to deal with businesses who do not subsequently comply with the policy. This is in contrast to agreements to maintain a certain price.
- United States v. Parke, Davis & Co., under Sherman Act §4
- Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Service Corp.,, stating that, "under Colgate, the manufacturer can announce its re-sale prices in advance and refuse to deal with those who fail to comply, and a distributor is free to acquiesce to the manufacturer's demand in order to avoid termination". Monsanto, an agricultural chemical, terminated its distributorship agreement with Spray-Rite on the ground that it failed to hire trained salesmen and promote sales to dealers adequately. Held, not per se illegal, because the restriction related to non-price matters, and so was to be judged under the rule of reason.
- Business Electronics Corp. v. Sharp Electronics Corp., electronic calculators; "a vertical restraint is not illegal per se unless it includes some agreement on price or price levels. ... here is a presumption in favor of a rule-of-reason standard; departure from that standard must be justified by demonstrable economic effect, such as the facilitation of cartelizing... "
Mergers
Dual antitrust enforcement by the Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission has long elicited concerns about disparate treatment of mergers. In response, in September 2014, the House Judiciary Committee approved the Standard Merger and Acquisition Reviews Through Equal Rules Act.
- FTC v. Dean Foods Co, 384 U.S. 597 5 to 4, the FTC was entitled to get an injunction to prevent the completion of a merger, between milk selling competitors in the Chicago area, before its competitive effects are determined by a court
- Robertson v. National Basketball Association, 556 F.2d 682 injunction issued against merger of the NBA with the ABA
- Citizen Publishing Co. v. United States, failing company defense
- Cargill, Inc. v. Monfort of Colorado, Inc, private enforcement
- Clayton Act 1914 §8, interlocking directorates
Horizontal mergers
- Northern Securities Co. v. United States, horizontal merger under the Sherman Act
- United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, the second and third largest of 42 banks in the Philadelphia area would lead to a 30% market control in a concentrated market, and so violated the Clayton Act §7. Banks were not exempt even though there was additional legislation under the Bank Merger Act of 1960.
- United States v. Von's Grocery Co., 384 U.S. 270 a merger of two grocery firms in the Los Angeles area did violate the Clayton Act §7, particularly considering the amendment by the Celler–Kefauver Act 1950
- United States v. General Dynamics Corp., 415 U.S. 486 General Dynamics Corp had taken control over, by share purchase, United Electric Coal Companies, a strip-mining coal producer.
- Horizontal Merger Guidelines
- FTC v. Staples, Inc., 970 F. Supp. 1066
- Hospital Corp. of America v. FTC, 807 F. 2d 1381
- Federal Trade Commission v. H.J. Heinz Co., 246 F.3d 708
- United States v. Oracle Corp, 331 F. Supp. 2d 1098
Vertical mergers
- United States v. Columbia Steel Co.,
- United States v. E.I. Du Pont De Nemours & Co.,
- Brown Shoe Co., Inc. v. United States, there is not one single test for whether a merger substantially lessens competition, but a variety of economic and other factors may be considered. Two shoe retailers and manufacturers merging was held to substantially lessen competition, given the market in towns over 10,000 people for men's, women's and children's shoes.
Conglomerate mergers
- United States v. Sidney W. Winslow,
- United States v. Continental Can Co., concerning the definition of the market segments in which the Continental Can Co was performing a merger.
- FTC v. Procter & Gamble Co.,
Monopoly and power
Monopolization
- Northern Securities Co. v. United States, 193 U.S. 197 5 to 4, a railway monopoly, formed through a merger of 3 corporations was ordered to be dissolved. The owner, James Jerome Hill was forced to manage his ownership stake in each independently.
- Swift & Co. v. United States, 196 U.S. 375 the antitrust laws entitled the federal government to regulate monopolies that had a direct impact on commerce
- Standard Oil Co. of New Jersey v. United States, 221 U.S. 1 Standard Oil was dismantled into geographical entities given its size, and that it was too much of a monopoly
- United States v. American Tobacco Company, 221 U.S. 106 found to have monopolized the trade.
- United States v. Alcoa, 148 F.2d 416 a monopoly can be deemed to exist depending on the size of the market. It was generally irrelevant how the monopoly was achieved since the fact of being dominant on the market was negative for competition.
- United States v. E. I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, illustrates the cellophane paradox of defining the relevant market. If a monopolist has set a price very high, there may now be many substitutable goods at similar prices, which could lead to a conclusion that the market share is small, and there is no monopoly. However, if a competitive price were charged, there would be a lower price, and so very few substitutes, whereupon the market share would be very high, and a monopoly established.
- United States v. Syufy Enterprises, 903 F.2d 659 necessity of barriers to entry
- Lorain Journal Co. v. United States, 342 U.S. 143 attempted monopolization
- United States v. American Airlines, Inc., 743 F.2d 1114
- Spectrum Sports, Inc. v. McQuillan, 506 U.S. 447 in order for monopolies to be found to have acted unlawfully, action must have actually been taken. The threat of abusive behavior is insufficient.
- Fraser v. Major League Soccer, 284 F.3d 47 there could be no unlawful monopolization of the soccer market by MLS where no market previously existed
- United States v. Griffith 334 U.S. 100 four cinema corporations secured exclusive rights from distributors, foreclosing competitors. Specific intent to monopolize is not required, violating the Sherman Act §§1 and 2.
- United Shoe Machinery Corp v. U.S., 347 U.S. 521 exclusionary behavior
- United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563 Grinnell made plumbing supplies and fire sprinklers, and with affiliates had 87% of the central station protective service market. From this predominant share there was no doubt of monopoly power.
Exclusive dealing
- Standard Oil Co. v. United States , 337 U.S. 293 : oil supply contracts affected a gross business of $58 million, comprising 6.7% of the total in a seven-state area, in the context of many similar arrangements, held to be contrary to Clayton Act §3.
- Tampa Electric Co. v. Nashville Coal Co., 365 U.S. 320 : Tampa Electric Co contracted to buy coal for 20 years to provide power in Florida, and Nashville Coal Co later attempted to end the contract on the basis that it was an exclusive supply agreement contrary to the Clayton Act § 3 or the Sherman Act §§ 1 or 2. Held, no violation because foreclosed share of market was insignificant this did not affect competition sufficiently.
- US v. Delta Dental of Rhode Island, 943 F. Supp. 172
Price discrimination
- Robinson–Patman Act
- Clayton Act 1914 §2
- FTC v. Morton Salt Co.
- Volvo Trucks North America, Inc. v. Reeder-Simco Gmc, Inc.
- J. Truett Payne Co. v. Chrysler Motors Corp.
- FTC v. Henry Broch & Co.
- FTC v. Borden Co., commodities of like grade and quality
- United States v. Borden Co., the cost justification defense
- United States v. United States Gypsum Co., meeting the competition defense
- Falls City Industries v. Vanco Beverage, Inc.
- Great Atlantic & Pacific Tea Co. v. FTC
Essential facilities
- Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 472 U.S. 585 the refusal of supply access to ski slopes violated the Sherman Act section 2.
- Eastman Kodak Company v. Image Technical Services, Inc., 504 U.S. 451 Kodak has refused to supply replacement parts to small businesses servicing Kodak equipment, which was alleged to violate the Sherman Act §§1 and 2. The Supreme Court held 6 to 3 that the small businesses were entitled to bring the case, and Kodak was not entitled to summary judgment.
- Verizon Communications v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398 no extension of the essential facilities doctrine beyond that set in Aspen
- Otter Tail Power Co. v. United States, 410 U.S. 366
- Berkey Photo, Inc v. Eastman Kodak Company, 603 F.2d 263
- United States v. AT&T led to the breakup of AT&T
Tying products
- Sherman Act 1890 §1, covers making purchase of goods conditional on purchase of other goods, if there is sufficient market power
- International Business Machines Corp. v. United States, requiring a leased machine to be operated only with supplies from IBM was contrary to Clayton Act §3.
- International Salt Co. v. United States, it would be a per se infringement of the Sherman Act §2 for a seller, who has a legal monopoly through a patent, to tie buyers to purchase products over which the seller does not have a patent
- United States v. Paramount Pictures, Inc., 334 US 131 Hollywood studios practice of requiring block booking was unlawful among other things
- Times-Picayune Publishing Co. v. United States, 345 U.S. 594 5 to 4, where there was no market dominance in a product market, tying the sale of a morning and an evening newspaper together was not unlawful
- United States v. Loew's Inc., 371 U.S. 38 product bundling and price discrimination. The existence of a tie was sufficient to create a presumption of market power.
- Jefferson Parish Hospital District No. 2 v. Hyde, reversing Loew's, it was necessary to prove sufficient market power for a tying requirement to be anti-competitive
- United States v. Microsoft Corporation and Microsoft ordered to be split into two for its monopolistic practices, including tying, but then the ruling was reversed by the Court of Appeals.
Predatory pricing
- Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209 to prove predatory pricing the plaintiff must show that changes in market conditions are adverse to its interests, and that prices are below an appropriate measure of its rival's costs, and the competitor had a reasonable prospect or a "dangerous probability" of recouping its investment in the alleged scheme.
- Weyerhaeuser Company v. Ross-Simmons Hardwood Lumber Company, 549 U.S. 312 a plaintiff must prove that, to make a claim of predatory buying, the alleged violator is likely to recoup the cost of the alleged predatory activity. This involved the saw mill market.
- Barry Wright Corp. v. ITT Grinnell Corp. 724 F2d 227
- Spirit Airlines, Inc. v. Northwest Airlines, Inc., 431 F. 3d 917
- United States v. E. I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377
Intellectual property
- Continental Paper Bag Co. v. Eastern Paper Bag Co., 210 U.S. 405 8 to 1, concerning a self opening paper bag, it was not an unlawful use of a monopoly position to refuse to license a patent's use to others, since the essence of a patent was the freedom not to do so.
- United States v. Univis Lens Co., 316 U.S. 241 once a business sold its patented lenses, it was not allowed to lawfully control the use of the lens, by fixing a price for resale. This was the exhaustion doctrine.
- International Salt Co. v. United States, 332 U.S. 392 it would be a per se infringement of the Sherman Act §2 for a seller, who has a legal monopoly through a patent, to tie buyers to purchase products over which the seller does not have a patent
- Walker Process Equipment, Inc. v. Food Machinery & Chemical Corp., 382 U.S. 172 illegal monopolization through the maintenance and enforcement of a patent obtained via fraud on the Patent Office case, sometimes called "Walker Process fraud".
- United States v. Glaxo Group Ltd., 410 U.S. 52 the government may challenge a patent where it is involved in a monopoly violation
- Illinois Tool Works Inc. v. Independent Ink, Inc., 547 U.S. 28 there is no presumption of market power, in a case on an unlawful tying arrangement, from the mere fact that the defendant has a patented product
- Apple Inc. litigation and United States v. Apple Inc.
Scope of antitrust law
Collective actions
First, since the Clayton Act 1914 §6, there is no application of antitrust laws to agreements between employees to form or act in labor unions. This was seen as the "Bill of Rights" for labor, as the Act laid down that the "labor of a human being is not a commodity or article of commerce". The purpose was to ensure that employees with unequal bargaining power were not prevented from combining in the same way that their employers could combine in corporations, subject to the restrictions on mergers that the Clayton Act set out. However, sufficiently autonomous workers, such as professional sports players have been held to fall within antitrust provisions.Pro sports exemptions and the NFL cartel
Second, professional sports leagues enjoy a number of exemptions. Mergers and joint agreements of professional football, hockey, baseball, and basketball leagues are exempt. Major League Baseball was held to be broadly exempt from antitrust law in Federal Baseball Club v. National League. Holmes J held that the baseball league's organization meant that there was no commerce between the states taking place, even though teams traveled across state lines to put on the games. That travel was merely incidental to a business which took place in each state. It was subsequently held in 1952 in Toolson v. New York Yankees, and then again in 1972 Flood v. Kuhn, that the baseball league's exemption was an "aberration". However Congress had accepted it, and favored it, so retroactively overruling the exemption was no longer a matter for the courts, but the legislature. In United States v. International Boxing Club of New York, it was held that, unlike baseball, boxing was not exempt, and in Radovich v. National Football League , professional football is generally subject to antitrust laws. As a result of the AFL-NFL merger, the National Football League was also given exemptions in exchange for certain conditions, such as not directly competing with college or high school football. However, the 2010 Supreme Court ruling in American Needle Inc. v. NFL characterised the NFL as a "cartel" of 32 independent businesses subject to antitrust law, not a single entity.Media
Third, antitrust laws are modified where they are perceived to encroach upon the media and free speech, or are not strong enough. Newspapers under joint operating agreements are allowed limited antitrust immunity under the Newspaper Preservation Act of 1970. More generally, and partly because of concerns about media cross-ownership in the United States, regulation of media is subject to specific statutes, chiefly the Communications Act of 1934 and the Telecommunications Act of 1996, under the guidance of the Federal Communications Commission. The historical policy has been to use the state's licensing powers over the airwaves to promote plurality. Antitrust laws do not prevent companies from using the legal system or political process to attempt to reduce competition. Most of these activities are considered legal under the Noerr-Pennington doctrine. Also, regulations by states may be immune under the Parker immunity doctrine.- Professional Real Estate Investors, Inc., v. Columbia Pictures, 508 U.S. 49
- Allied Tube v. Indian Head, Inc., 486 U.S. 492
- FTC v. Superior Ct. TLA, 493 U.S. 411
Other
Fifth, insurance is allowed limited antitrust exemptions as provided by the McCarran-Ferguson Act of 1945.
Sixth, M&A transactions in the defense sector are often subject to greater antitrust scrutiny from the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission.
- United States v. South-Eastern Underwriters Association, 322 U.S. 533 the insurance industry was not exempt from antitrust regulation.
- Credit Suisse v. Billing, 551 U.S. 264 7 to 1, the industries regulated by the Securities Act 1933 and the Securities and Exchange Act 1934 are exempt from antitrust lawsuits.
- Parker v. Brown, 317 U.S. 341 actions by state governments were held to be exempt from antitrust law, given that there was no original legislative intent to cover anything other than business combinations.
- Goldfarb v. Virginia State Bar, 421 U.S. 773 the Virginia State Bar, which was delegated power to set price schedules for lawyers fees, was an unlawful price fixing. It was no longer exempt from the Sherman Act, and constituted a per se infringement.
- California Retail Liquor Dealers Assn. v. Midcal Aluminum, Inc., 445 U.S. 97 the state of California acted contrary to the Sherman Act 1890 §1 by setting fair trade wine price schedules
- Rice v. Norman Williams Co., 458 U.S. 654 the Sherman Act did not prohibit a California law which prohibited the importation of goods that were not authorised to be imported by the manufacturer
- Tritent International Corp. v. Commonwealth of Kentucky, 467 F.3d 547 Kentucky had not acted unlawfully by giving effect to a Tobacco Master Settlement Agreement, because there was no illegal behavior in it
- United States v. Trans-Missouri Freight Association, 166 U.S. 290 the antitrust laws applied to the railroad industry, even though there was a comprehensive scheme of legislation applying to the railroads already. No specific exemption had been given.
- Silver v. New York Stock Exchange, 373 U.S. 341 the NYSE was not exempt from antitrust regulation, even though many of its activities were regulated by the Securities and Exchange Act 1934
- American Society of Mechanical Engineers v. Hydrolevel Corporation, 456 U.S. 556 6 to 3, that the American Society of Mechanical Engineers, a non profit standard developer had violated the Sherman Act by giving information to one competitor, used against another.
- Banks and agricultural cooperatives.
Remedies and enforcement
Federal government
The federal government, via both the Antitrust Division of the United States Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission, can bring civil lawsuits enforcing the laws. The United States Department of Justice alone may bring criminal antitrust suits under federal antitrust laws. Perhaps the most famous antitrust enforcement actions brought by the federal government were the break-up of AT&T's local telephone service monopoly in the early 1980s and its actions against Microsoft in the late 1990s.Additionally, the federal government also reviews potential mergers to attempt to prevent market concentration. As outlined by the Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust Improvements Act, larger companies attempting to merge must first notify the Federal Trade Commission and the Department of Justice's Antitrust Division prior to consummating a merger. These agencies then review the proposed merger first by defining what the market is and then determining the market concentration using the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index and each company's market share. The government looks to avoid allowing a company to develop market power, which if left unchecked could lead to monopoly power.
The United States Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission target nonreportable mergers for enforcement as well. Notably, between 2009 and 2013, 20% of all merger investigations conducted by the United States Department of Justice involved nonreportable transactions.
- FTC v. Sperry & Hutchinson Trading Stamp Co., 405 U.S. 233. Case held that the FTC is entitled to bring enforcement action against businesses that act unfairly, as where supermarket trading stamps company injured consumers by prohibiting them from exchanging trading stamps. The FTC could prevent the restrictive practice as unfair, even though there was no specific antitrust violation.
International cooperation
In many cases large US companies tend to deal with overseas antitrust within the overseas jurisdiction, autonomous of US laws, such as in Microsoft Corp v Commission and more recently, Google v European Union where the companies were heavily fined. Questions have been raised with regards to the consistency of antitrust between jurisdictions where the same antitrust corporate behaviour, and similar antitrust legal environment, is prosecuted in one jurisdiction but not another.
State governments
may file suits to enforce both state and federal antitrust laws.- Parens patriae
- Hawaii v. Standard Oil Co. of Cal., 405 U.S. 251 state governments do not have a cause of action to sue for consequential loss for damage to their general economies after an antitrust violation is found.
Private suits
- Pfizer, Inc. v. Government of India, 434 U.S. 308 foreign governments have standing to sue in private actions in the U.S. courts.
- Bigelow v. RKO Radio Pictures, Inc., 327 U.S. 251 treble damages awarded under the Clayton Act §4 needed not to be mathematically precise, but based on a reasonable estimate of loss, and not speculative. This meant a jury could set a higher estimate of how much movie theaters lost, when the film distributors conspired with other theaters to let them show films first.
- Illinois Brick Co. v. Illinois, 431 U.S. 720 indirect purchasers of goods where prices have been raised have no standing to sue. Only the direct contractors of cartel members may, to avoid double or multiple recovery.
- Mitsubishi Motors Corp. v. Soler Chrysler-Plymouth, Inc., 473 U.S. 614 on arbitration
Theory
By contrast, efficiency argue that antitrust legislation should be changed to primarily benefit consumers, and have no other purpose. Free market economist Milton Friedman states that he initially agreed with the underlying principles of antitrust laws, but that he came to the conclusion that they do more harm than good. Thomas Sowell argues that, even if a superior business drives out a competitor, it does not follow that competition has ended:
Alan Greenspan argues that the very existence of antitrust laws discourages businessmen from some activities that might be socially useful out of fear that their business actions will be determined illegal and dismantled by government. In his essay entitled Antitrust, he says: "No one will ever know what new products, processes, machines, and cost-saving mergers failed to come into existence, killed by the Sherman Act before they were born. No one can ever compute the price that all of us have paid for that Act which, by inducing less effective use of capital, has kept our standard of living lower than would otherwise have been possible." Those, like Greenspan, who oppose antitrust tend not to support competition as an end in itself but for its results—low prices. As long as a monopoly is not a coercive monopoly where a firm is securely insulated from potential competition, it is argued that the firm must keep prices low in order to discourage competition from arising. Hence, legal action is uncalled for and wrongly harms the firm and consumers.
Thomas DiLorenzo, an adherent of the Austrian School of economics, found that the "trusts" of the late 19th century were dropping their prices faster than the rest of the economy, and he holds that they were not monopolists at all. Ayn Rand, the American writer, provides a moral argument against antitrust laws. She holds that these laws in principle criminalize any person engaged in making a business successful, and, thus, are gross violations of their individual expectations. Such laissez faire advocates suggest that only a coercive monopoly should be broken up, that is the persistent, exclusive control of a vitally needed resource, good, or service such that the community is at the mercy of the controller, and where there are no suppliers of the same or substitute goods to which the consumer can turn. In such a monopoly, the monopolist is able to make pricing and production decisions without an eye on competitive market forces and is able to curtail production to price-gouge consumers. Laissez-faire advocates argue that such a monopoly can only come about through the use of physical coercion or fraudulent means by the corporation or by government intervention and that there is no case of a coercive monopoly ever existing that was not the result of government policies.
Judge Robert Bork's writings on antitrust law, along with those of Richard Posner and other law and economics thinkers, were heavily influential in causing a shift in the U.S. Supreme Court's approach to antitrust laws since the 1970s, to be focused solely on what is best for the consumer rather than the company's practices.
Texts
- ET Sullivan, H Hovenkamp and HA Shlanski, Antitrust Law, Policy and Procedure: Cases, Materials, Problems
- CJ Goetz, FS McChesney and TA Lambert, Antitrust Law, Interpretation and Implementation
- P Areeda and L Kaplow, Antitrust Analysis: Problems, Texts, Cases
Theory
- W Adams and JW Brock, Antitrust Economics on Trial: Dialogue in New Learning .
- O Black, Conceptual Foundations of Antitrust
- RH Bork, The Antitrust Paradox .
- Antonio Cucinotta, ed. Post-Chicago Developments in Antitrust Law
- David S Evans. Microsoft, Antitrust and the New Economy: Selected Essays
- John E Kwoka and Lawrence J White, eds. The Antitrust Revolution: Economics, Competition, and Policy
- RA Posner, Antitrust Law: An Economic Perspective
Articles
- AA Berle, 'Corporate Powers as Powers in Trust' 44 Harvard Law Review 1049
- AA Berle, 'The Theory of Enterprise Entity' 47 Columbia Law Review 343
- AA Berle, 'The Developing Law of Corporate Concentration'
- AA Berle, 'Property, Production and Revolution'
- Herbert Hovenkamp, 'Chicago and Its Alternatives' 6 Duke Law Journal 1014–1029
- B Orbach and G Campbell, , Southern California Law Review.
- R Hofstadter, "What Ever Happened to the Antitrust Movement?" in The Paranoid Style in American Politics and Other Essays..
- RJR Peritz, 'Three Visions of Managed Competition, 1920–1950' 39 Antitrust Bulletin 273–287.
Historical
- Adolf Berle and Gardiner Means, The Modern Corporation and Private Property
- Louis Brandeis, The Curse of Bigness
- Alfred Chandler, The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business
- J Dirlam and A Kahn, Fair Competition: The Law and Economics of Antitrust Policy
- J Dorfman, The Economic Mind in American Civilization 1865–1918
- T Freyer, Regulating Big Business: Antitrust in Great Britain and America, 1880–1990
- W Hamilton & I Till, Antitrust in Action
- W Letwin, Law and Economic Policy in America: The Evolution of the Sherman Antitrust Act
- E Rozwenc, ed. Roosevelt, Wilson and The Trusts.
- George Stigler, The Organization of Industry
- G Stocking and M Watkins, Monopoly and Free Enterprise.
- H Thorelli, The Federal Antitrust Policy: Origination of an American Tradition
- S Webb and B Webb, Industrial Democracy