Schools of economic thought
In the history of economic thought, a school of economic thought is a group of economic thinkers who share or shared a common perspective on the way economies work. While economists do not always fit into particular schools, particularly in modern times, classifying economists into schools of thought is common. Economic thought may be roughly divided into three phases: premodern, early modern and modern. Systematic economic theory has been developed mainly since the beginning of what is termed the modern era.
Currently, the great majority of economists follow an approach referred to as mainstream economics. Economists generally specialize into either macroeconomics, broadly on the general scope of the economy as a whole, and microeconomics, on specific markets or actors.
Within the macroeconomic mainstream in the United States, distinctions can be made between saltwater economists and the more laissez-faire ideas of freshwater economists. However, there is broad agreement on the importance of general equilibrium, the methodology related to models used for certain purposes, and the importance of partial equilibrium models for analyzing specific factors important to the economy.
Some influential approaches of the past, such as the historical school of economics and institutional economics, have become defunct or have declined in influence, and are now considered heterodox approaches. Other longstanding heterodox schools of economic thought include Austrian economics and Marxian economics. Some more recent developments in economic thought such as feminist economics and ecological economics adapt and critique mainstream approaches with an emphasis on particular issues rather than developing as independent schools.
Contemporary economic thought
Mainstream economics
Mainstream economics is distinguished in general economics from heterodox approaches and schools within economics. It begins with the premise that resources are scarce and that it is necessary to choose between competing alternatives. That is, economics deals with tradeoffs. With scarcity, choosing one alternative implies forgoing another alternative—the opportunity cost. The opportunity cost expresses an implicit relationship between competing alternatives. Such costs, considered as prices in a market economy, are used for analysis of economic efficiency or for predicting responses to disturbances in a market. In a planned economy comparable shadow price relations must be satisfied for the efficient use of resources, as first demonstrated by the Italian economist Enrico Barone.Economists believe that incentives and costs play a pervasive role in shaping decision making. An immediate example of this is the consumer theory of individual demand, which isolates how prices and income affect quantity demanded. Modern mainstream economics builds primarily on neoclassical economics, which began to develop in the late 19th century. Mainstream economics also acknowledges the existence of market failure and insights from Keynesian economics. It uses models of economic growth for analyzing long-run variables affecting national income. It employs game theory for modeling market or non-market behavior. Some important insights on collective behavior have been incorporated through the new institutional economics. A definition that captures much of modern economics is that of Lionel Robbins in a 1932 essay: "the science which studies human behaviour as a relationship between ends and scarce means which have alternative uses." Scarcity means that available resources are insufficient to satisfy all wants and needs. Absent scarcity and alternative uses of available resources, there is no economic problem. The subject thus defined involves the study of choice, as affected by incentives and resources.
Mainstream economics encompasses a wide range of views. Politically, most mainstream economists hold views ranging from laissez-faire to modern liberalism. There are also divergent views on particular issues within economics, such as the effectiveness and desirability of Keynesian macroeconomic policy. Although, historically, few mainstream economists have regarded themselves as members of a "school", many would identify with one or more of neoclassical economics, monetarism, Keynesian economics, new classical economics, or behavioral economics.
Controversies within mainstream economics tend to be stated in terms of:
- the completeness of markets and contracting opportunities;
- the existence or significance of asymmetric information problems;
- the importance of deviations from optimizing behaviour of economic agents; and
- the role of externalities or public goods.
Contemporary heterodox economics
In the late 19th century, a number of heterodox schools contended with the neoclassical school that arose following the marginal revolution. Most survive to the present day as self-consciously dissident schools, but with greatly diminished size and influence relative to mainstream economics. The most significant are Institutional economics, Marxian economics and the Austrian School.
The development of Keynesian economics was a substantial challenge to the dominant neoclassical school of economics. Keynesian views eventually entered the mainstream as a result of the Keynesian-neoclassical synthesis developed by John Hicks. The rise of Keynesianism, and its incorporation into mainstream economics, reduced the appeal of heterodox schools. However, advocates of a more fundamental critique of orthodox economics formed a school of Post-Keynesian economics.
More recent heterodox developments include evolutionary economics, feminist, Green economics, Post-autistic economics, and Thermoeconomics.
Heterodox approaches often embody criticisms of the "mainstream" approaches. For instance:
- feminist economics criticizes the valuation of labor and argues female labor is systemically undervalued;
- green economics criticizes externalized and intangible status of ecosystems and argues to bring them within the tangible measured capital asset model as natural capital; and
- post-autistic economics criticizes the focus on formal models at the expense of observation and values, arguing for a return to moral philosophy.
Georgescu-Roegen reintroduced into economics, the concept of entropy from thermodynamics and did foundational work which later developed into evolutionary economics. His work contributed significantly to thermoeconomics and to ecological economics.
Other viewpoints on economic issues from outside mainstream economics include dependency theory and world systems theory in the study of international relations.
Proposed radical reforms of the economic system originating outside mainstream economics include the participatory economics movement and binary economics.
Historical economic thought
Modern macro- and microeconomics are young sciences. But many in the past have thought on topics ranging from value to production relations. These forays into economic thought contribute to the modern understanding, ranging from ancient Greek conceptions of the role of the household and its choices to mercantilism and its emphasis on the hoarding of precious metals.Ancient economic thought
- Chanakya
- Xenophon
- Aristotle
- Qin Shi Huang
- Wang Anshi
Islamic economics
Islamic economics seeks to enforce Islamic regulations not only on personal issues, but to implement broader economic goals and policies of an Islamic society, based on uplifting the deprived masses. It was founded on free and unhindered circulation of wealth so as to handsomely reach even the lowest echelons of society. One distinguishing feature is the tax on wealth, and bans levying taxes on all kinds of trade and transactions.
Another distinguishing feature is prohibition of interest in the form of excess charged while trading in money. Its pronouncement on
use of paper currency also stands out. Though promissory notes are recognized, they must be fully backed by reserves. Fractional-reserve banking is disallowed as a form of breach of trust.
It saw innovations such as trading companies, big businesses, contracts, bills of exchange, long-distance international trade, the first forms of partnership such as limited partnerships, and the earliest forms of credit, debt, profit, loss, capital, capital accumulation, circulating capital, capital expenditure, revenue, cheques, promissory notes, trusts, startup companies, savings accounts, transactional accounts, pawning, loaning, exchange rates, bankers, money changers, ledgers, deposits, assignments, the double-entry bookkeeping system, lawsuits, and agency institution.
This school has seen a revived interest in development and understanding since the later part of the 20th century.
- Muhammad
- Abu Hanifa an-Nu‘man
- Abu Yusuf
- Al-Farabi
- Shams al-Mo'ali Abol-hasan Ghaboos ibn Wushmgir
- Ibn Sina
- Ibn Miskawayh
- Al-Ghazali
- Ibn Taymiyyah
- Al-Mawardi
- Nasīr al-Dīn al-Tūsī
- Ibn Khaldun
- Al-Maqrizi
- Muhammad Baqir al-Sadr
Scholasticism
- Nicole Oresme
- Thomas Aquinas
- School of Salamanca
- Leonardus Lessius
Mercantilism
- Gerard de Malynes
- Edward Misselden
- Thomas Mun
- Jean Bodin
- Jean Baptiste Colbert
- Josiah Child
- William Petty
- John Locke
- Charles Davenant
- Dudley North
- Ferdinando Galiani
- James Denham-Steuart
Physiocrats
- Anne Robert Jacques Turgot
- François Quesnay
- Pierre le Pesant de Boisguilbert
- Richard Cantillon
Classical political economy
- Henry George
- Francis Hutcheson
- Bernard de Mandeville
- David Hume
- Adam Smith
- Thomas Malthus
- James Mill
- Francis Place
- David Ricardo
- Henry Thornton
- John Ramsay McCulloch
- James Maitland, 8th Earl of Lauderdale
- Jeremy Bentham
- Jean Charles Léonard de Sismondi
- Johann Heinrich von Thünen
- John Stuart Mill
- Karl Marx
- Nassau William Senior
- Edward Gibbon Wakefield
- John Rae
- Thomas Tooke
- Robert Torrens
American (National) School
- Alexander Hamilton
- John Quincy Adams
- Henry Clay
- Mathew Carey
- Henry Charles Carey
- Abraham Lincoln
- Friedrich List
- Otto Von Bismarck
- Arthur Griffith
- William McKinley
French liberal school
- Frédéric Bastiat
- Maurice Block
- Pierre Paul Leroy-Beaulieu
- Gustave de Molinari
- Yves Guyot
- Jean-Baptiste Say
- Léon Say
German historical school
Predecessors included Friedrich List. The Historical school largely controlled appointments to Chairs of Economics in German universities, as many of the advisors of Friedrich Althoff, head of the university department in the Prussian Ministry of Education 1882-1907, had studied under members of the School. Moreover, Prussia was the intellectual powerhouse of Germany and so dominated academia, not only in central Europe, but also in the United States until about 1900, because the American economics profession was led by holders of German Ph.Ds. The Historical school was involved in the Methodenstreit with the Austrian School, whose orientation was more theoretical and a prioristic. In English speaking countries, the Historical school is perhaps the least known and least understood approach to the study of economics, because it differs radically from the now-dominant Anglo-American analytical point of view. Yet the Historical school forms the basis—both in theory and in practice—of the social market economy, for many decades the dominant economic paradigm in most countries of continental Europe. The Historical school is also a source of Joseph Schumpeter's dynamic, change-oriented, and innovation-based economics. Although his writings could be critical of the School, Schumpeter's work on the role of innovation and entrepreneurship can be seen as a continuation of ideas originated by the Historical School, especially the work of von Schmoller and Sombart.
- Wilhelm Roscher
- Gustav von Schmoller
- Werner Sombart
- Max Weber
- Joseph Schumpeter
- Karl Polanyi
English historical school
- Edmund Burke
- Richard Jones
- Thomas Edward Cliffe Leslie
- Walter Bagehot
- Thorold Rogers
- William J. Ashley
- William Cunningham
French historical school
- Clement Juglar
- Charles Gide
- Albert Aftalion
- Émile Levasseur
- François Simiand
Utopian economics
- William Godwin
- Charles Fourier
- Robert Owen
- Saint-Simon
Georgist economics
- Harry Gunnison Brown
- Raymond Crotty
- Ottmar Edenhofer
- Fred Foldvary
- Mason Gaffney
- Henry George
- Max Hirsch
- Wolf Ladejinsky
- Philippe Legrain
- Donald Shoup
- Nicolaus Tideman
Ricardian socialism
- John Francis Bray
- John Gray
- Charles Hall
- Thomas Hodgskin
- William Thompson
Marxian economics
- Eduard Bernstein
- Richard D. Wolff
- David Harvey
- Karl Marx
- Friedrich Engels
Neo-Marxian economics
- David Gordon
- Samuel Bowles
- Paul A. Baran
- Adam Przeworski
- Henryk Grossman
State socialism
- Henri de Saint-Simon
- Ferdinand Lassalle
- Johann Karl Rodbertus
- Fabian Society
Anarchist economics
- Mutualists advocate market socialism.
- Collectivist anarchists advocate workers cooperatives and salaries based on the amount of time contributed to production.
- Anarcho-communists advocate a direct transition from capitalism to libertarian communism and a gift economy with direct communal democracy.
- Anarcho-syndicalists advocate worker's direct action and the general strike.
Distributism is an economic philosophy that was originally formulated in the late 19th century and early 20th century by Catholic thinkers to reflect the teachings of Pope Leo XIII's encyclical Rerum Novarum and Pope Pius's XI encyclical Quadragesimo Anno. It seeks to pursue a third way between capitalism and socialism, desiring to order society according to Christian principles of justice while still preserving private property.
- G. K. Chesterton
- Hilaire Belloc
Institutional economics
- Gunnar Myrdal
- Thorstein Veblen
- John Rogers Commons
- Wesley Clair Mitchell
- John Maurice Clark
- Robert A. Brady
- Clarence Edwin Ayres
- Romesh Dutt
- John Kenneth Galbraith
- Geoffrey Hodgson
- Ha-Joon Chang
Neoclassical economics
- William Stanley Jevons
- Francis Ysidro Edgeworth
- Alfred Marshall
- John Bates Clark
- Irving Fisher
- Knut Wicksell
Lausanne school
- Antoine Augustin Cournot
- Léon Walras
- Vilfredo Pareto
Austrian school
- Carl Menger
- Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk
- Ludwig von Mises
- Friedrich Hayek
- Friedrich von Wieser
- Henry Hazlitt
- Frank Fetter
- Israel Kirzner
- Murray Rothbard
- Robert P. Murphy
- Lew Rockwell
- Peter Schiff
- Marc Faber
- Walter Block
- Hans Hermann-Hoppe
- Jesús Huerta de Soto
- Fritz Machlup
Stockholm school
The Stockholm School had—like John Maynard Keynes—come to the same conclusions in macroeconomics and the theories of demand and supply. Like Keynes, they were inspired by the works of Knut Wicksell, a Swedish economist active in the early years of the twentieth century.
- Gunnar Myrdal
- Bertil Ohlin
Keynesian economics
- John Maynard Keynes
- Joan Robinson
- Paul Krugman
- Paul Samuelson
- Peter Bofinger
- Joseph Stiglitz
- Nouriel Roubini
- Stanley Fischer
- Gregory Mankiw
- Jason Furman
- Huw Dixon
Chicago school
- Frank H. Knight
- Jacob Viner
- Milton Friedman
- Thomas Sowell
- George Stigler
- Harry Markowitz
- Merton Miller
- Robert Lucas, Jr.
- Eugene Fama
- Myron Scholes
- Gary Becker
- Edward C. Prescott
- James Heckman
- Robert Z. Aliber
Carnegie school
- Herbert A. Simon
- Richard Cyert
- James March
- Victor Vroom
- Oliver E. Williamson
- John Muth
Neo-Ricardianism
- Piero Sraffa
- Luigi L. Pasinetti
- Vladimir Karpovich Dmitriev
New institutional economics
- Douglass North
- Oliver E. Williamson
- Ronald Coase
- Daron Acemoglu
- Steven N. S. Cheung
20th century schools
- Austrian School
- Biological economics
- Chicago School
- Constitutional economics
- Ecological economics
- Evolutionary economics
- Free-market anarchism
- Freiburg School
- Freiwirtschaft
- Georgism
- Institutional economics
- Keynesian economics
- Marxian and neo-Marxian economics
- Neo-Ricardianism
- New classical macroeconomics
- New Keynesian economics
- Post-Keynesian economics
- Public Choice school
- School of Lausanne
- Stockholm school
The study of risk was influential, in viewing variations in price over time as more important than actual price. This applied particularly to financial economics, where risk/return tradeoffs were the crucial decisions to be made.
An important area of growth was the study of information and decision. Examples of this school included the work of Joseph Stiglitz. Problems of asymmetric information and moral hazard, both based around information economics, profoundly affected modern economic dilemmas like executive stock options, insurance markets, and Third-World debt relief.
Finally, there were a series of economic ideas rooted in the conception of economics as a branch of biology, including the idea that energy relationships, rather than price relationships, determine economic structure. The use of fractal geometry to create economic models. In its infancy the application of non-linear dynamics to economic theory, as well as the application of evolutionary psychology explored the processes of valuation and the persistence of non-equilibrium conditions. The most visible work was in the area of applying fractals to market analysis, particularly arbitrage. Another infant branch of economics was neuroeconomics. The latter combines neuroscience, economics, and psychology to study how we make choices.